Along the Mekong, conservation-payment schemes are a study in contrasts

This article posts during GLF 2014. See in English | Espanol
Sunset over the Mekong River, near Luang Prabang, Laos, Photo: Jason Devitt/Flickr
Sunset over the Mekong River, near Luang Prabang, Laos, Photo: Jason Devitt/Flickr

By Adinda Hasan, originally published at Forests News

One river, many ways to protect its forests—but are those ways effective? A recent workshop on incentive-based conservation in four Southeast Asian countries explored the diversity of approaches being employed—and highlighted worries about their long-term viability.

In the Mekong River region, the concept of Payment for Environmental Services (PES) has gained attention as a cost-effective and innovative means of promoting sustainable environmental management while improving livelihoods. Yet, a comparison of schemes highlights emerging concerns over equity for participants, financial sustainability of initiatives, and the need to measure environmental and social outcomes.

A series of studies by the Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR) of PES schemes in  Cambodia,  Laos,  Thailand  and Vietnam, found that far from being market-driven, most PES initiatives are primarily funded by government, donor and civil society organizations.

Vietnam is a distinct example where the private sector is mandated to make payments for the use of environmental services, with the costs passed down to the end users—the consumers

PES was conceived as a voluntary, conditional transaction for a well-defined ecological service. Yet, Vietnam—which has the most developed PES scheme in the region and generates tens of millions of dollars annually—requires water supply, hydropower and tourist companies to pay fixed rates. These funds are distributed to the environmental services providers, which include state companies and villagers as they conserve forests for watershed protection and landscape aesthetics.

“Vietnam is a distinct example where the private sector is mandated to make payments for the use of environmental services, with the costs passed down to the end users—the consumers,” explained CIFOR scientist Jacob Phelps at a recent regional PES workshop in Hanoi.

The situation differs elsewhere in the region. In Thailand, corporate social responsibility investments protect ecosystem services such as fresh water and are implemented mostly by government agencies, with initial funding by international donors. In Laos, after significant pressure from the World Bank, a government hydropower project has set yearly payments of USD 1 million of dam revenues to protect the watershed. And some projects in Cambodia and Laos target biodiversity conservation, based on PES schemes led by non-governmental organizations (NGOs) linked to eco-tourism projects. In these schemes, communities are paid additional premiums if tourists successfully encounter target species such as tigers and deer.

THE ‘P’ IN ‘PES’

At the Hanoi workshop, Phelps elaborated on the implications of ad hoc, local projects funded by donors and NGOs in Laos, Cambodia and Thailand. “These represent many promising examples and models, but it will not necessarily lead to a massive scaling up,” he said. “We need to be realistic about how and who is going to pay. This is a major issue because there’s no such thing as PES if there’s no ‘P.’ ”

Workshop participants noted that developing a national policy framework that provides guidance and ensures compliance would be key to achieving sustainability for PES. Yet, further capacity building and awareness-raising is needed on the economic value of ecosystem services.

Chea Sokhon, Secretary of the Climate Change Working Group under Cambodia’s Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries remarked, “There is no policy framework for formulating PES. People’s understanding of PES and ecosystem services is very limited. PES is seen as reaping low economic returns compared with greater economic opportunities in agriculture and infrastructure development.

“Even supportive policymakers are hesitant about the costs of developing payment mechanisms. Identifying buyers and assessing their willingness to pay is a key concern.”

Read full blog here